Carl Menger
Our editors will review what you’ve submitted and determine whether to revise the article.
- Born:
- February 23, 1840, Neu-Sandec, Galicia, Austrian Empire [now Nowy Sącz, Poland]
- Subjects Of Study:
- marginal utility
- exchange value
Carl Menger (born February 23, 1840, Neu-Sandec, Galicia, Austrian Empire [now Nowy Sącz, Poland]—died February 26, 1921, Vienna, Austria) was an Austrian economist who contributed to the development of the marginal utility theory and to the formulation of a subjective theory of value.
Menger received a Ph.D. from the Jagiellonian University in Kraków in 1867 and then accepted a position in the Austrian civil service. In 1873 he became a professor of political economy at the University of Vienna, remaining there, with brief interruptions, until 1903. He then devoted himself to his studies in economics. Menger was widely known as the founder of the Austrian school of economics.
What made Menger (along with economists William Stanley Jevons and Léon Walras) a founder of the marginal utility revolution was the insight that goods are valuable because they serve various uses whose importance differs. Menger used this insight to resolve the diamond-water paradox that Adam Smith had posed but did not solve in The Wealth of Nations (1776). (See Austrian school of economics.) Menger also used it to refute the view popularized by David Ricardo and Karl Marx that the value of goods derives from the value of labour used to produce them. Menger proved just the opposite: that the value of labour derives from the value of the goods it produces, which is why, for example, the best professional basketball players or most popular actors are paid so much.
Menger also used the subjective theory of value to disprove the Aristotelian view that exchange involves a transaction of equal value for equal value. In exchange, Menger pointed out, people will give up what they value less in return for what they value more, which is why both sides can gain from an exchange. That led him to the conclusion that middlemen create value by facilitating exchange. Menger also showed that money, as a transactional medium, solves the difficulty of exchanging goods directly: a chicken farmer who wants gasoline finds it easier to trade those chickens for some widely accepted good—money—and then to trade this good for gasoline. It is far more difficult to trade chickens directly for gasoline. Money, like language, developed naturally as a means for facilitating human interaction.